Park the Employment Relations Law Reform Bill
20 May 2004
Park the Employment Relations Law Reform Bill and start over
“The Employment Relations Law Reform Bill should be parked and a new reform process should be instituted with genuine consultation among all stakeholders, including business”, according to New Zealand Business Roundtable executive director Roger Kerr.
Mr Kerr was commenting following the Business Roundtable’s appearance before the Transport and Industrial Relations Committee, which is studying the bill.
The Business Roundtable expressed concerns about a number of aspects of the bill, including changes to the definition of good faith, changes to personal grievance provisions, measures in the bill aimed at promoting compulsory unionism, collective bargaining and national awards and the provisions relating to the transfer or sale of a business.
It also put forward a number of suggestions for improvements to the existing labour legislation, including removing the union monopoly on bargaining, introducing a probationary period for newly hired workers and placing a salary bar on unjustified dismissal claims.
“The focus of the debate over the proposed changes to the Employment Relations Act should not be on how bad it is – whether we’re just shooting a hole in our foot or blowing a whole leg off (hardly anyone is arguing it would be good for the economy overall).
“Rather the focus should be on about how we can make our employment law better to regain lost international competitiveness and promote faster economic growth, which the government says is its top priority. We need to move forward, not back,” concluded Mr Kerr.
The Business Roundtable submission is below:
ENDS
NEW ZEALAND
BUSINESS ROUNDTABLE
Submission on the Employment
Relations Law Reform Bill
February 2004
Executive Summary
• This submission on the Employment
Relations Law Reform Bill (the bill) is made by the New
Zealand Business Roundtable (NZBR), an organisation
comprising primarily chief executives of major New Zealand
business firms. The purpose of the NZBR is to contribute to
the development of sound public policies that reflect
overall New Zealand interests.
• The submission
provides a high level assessment of the bill and draws out a
number of implications of the proposed changes.
• The
bill amends a number of areas of the Employment Relations
Act (ERA), including the definition of good faith,
provisions relating to collective bargaining, the resolution
of employment relationship problems and protection of
employees when businesses are sold.
• Although the
minister of labour has dubbed the bill a ‘fine-tuning’ of
the ERA, the proposed changes are comprehensive and would
constitute a significant alteration of the labour relations
landscape in New Zealand.
• In our view, the bill
represents poor public policy and should be withdrawn. We
have several concerns with the proposed changes:
(i) they lack a sound policy basis. In particular, they
do not recognise the realities of the modern labour market
and are a step back toward compulsory unionism, compulsory
arbitration and national awards;
(ii) they would
significantly worsen the business environment in New Zealand
and have an adverse impact on New Zealand’s growth prospects
and its ability to return to the top half of the OECD income
rankings; and
(iii) the process used to develop the bill
has been flawed and has been dominated by the Council of
Trade Unions (CTU), with little engagement being sought with
business.
• The government has stated that economic growth "remains a top policy priority”. The proposed changes to the ERA will do nothing to lift growth and are likely to reduce it. This should be the central consideration of the Committee in addressing the bill.
• Collectively, the
proposed changes to the ERA will mean a less flexible
workforce, through the promotion of collective bargaining,
unionisation and multi-employer collective agreements. They
will expand the role of third parties in labour relations
and will increase compliance costs.
• The changes
represent a further move toward a ‘European’ model of labour
market regulation. This is occurring at the very time that
the weaknesses in that model are becoming more obvious in
countries such as France, Italy and Germany and commentators
are recommending wholesale changes to it.
• There is
evidence that strict employment protection policies reduce
growth and hamper innovation. The proposed changes are
therefore at odds with the government’s innovation focus
under the Growth and Innovation Framework.
• In its
assessment of the bill, we recommend that the committee not
get lost in its complex detail. It should instead focus on
the ‘big picture’. The fundamental question to be asked of
the proposed changes to the ERA is whether they will promote
a more prosperous New Zealand.
• We support the
detailed submissions of Business New Zealand on the clauses
of the bill. However, in our view the proposed changes will
not promote New Zealand’s prosperity. We think the bill
should be withdrawn and a fundamental review of the
Employment Relations Act and its underlying principles
should be undertaken. The review should address weaknesses
in the current labour relations legal framework and involve
inputs from all interested parties.
1. Introduction
1.1 This submission on the Employment
Relations Law Reform Bill (the bill) is made by the New
Zealand Business Roundtable (NZBR), an organisation
comprising primarily chief executives of major New Zealand
business firms. The purpose of the NZBR is to contribute to
the development of sound public policies that reflect
overall New Zealand interests.
1.2 A national interest
perspective requires that account be taken of the interests
of many groups, including consumers, employees, the
unemployed, employers and investors. The tension is not
between the interests of firms and employees, as is often
suggested. Trying to establish whether a particular feature
of labour law is ‘business friendly’ or ‘worker friendly’ is
to adopt the wrong criterion. So-called ‘worker protection’
rules, for example, which raise the costs and risks of
employment, typically hurt workers as a group, the
unemployed and consumers, rather than employers, at least
beyond the short run. If the costs and risks of employing
staff go up, firms will have to offset them in one way or
another to maintain competitive returns on investment. This
is particularly true in today’s open capital markets. Thus
it is quite superficial to view any provisions in the bill,
or their removal, as a ‘win’ for either workers or
employers. The proper national interest criteria to be
applied are whether a measure contributes to efficiency (a
more productive economy), equity (in relation to all
parties, and in particular marginal workers and the
unemployed) and individual freedom (a minimum of state
interference with people’s choices).
1.3 This
submission provides a high level assessment of the bill and
draws out a number of implications of the proposed changes.
It does not provide a detailed clause-by-clause assessment
of the bill. For such an assessment, we would commend the
comprehensive and detailed submission provided to the
committee by Business New Zealand.
1.4 Section 2
outlines the key elements of the bill. Section 3 provides
an assessment of the proposed changes included in the bill.
Section 4 presents our conclusions and recommendations.
2. Experience with the Employment Relations
Act
2.1 It is often argued that the experience with the
Employment Relations Act (ERA) has been satisfactory and
that a further tightening of employment relations law would
not have an adverse impact on the New Zealand economy. Such
a view needs to be questioned for several reasons.
Experience under the ERA has not been positive and it may
not provide a good indicator of the potential impact of the
changes proposed in the bill.
2.2 First, some of the
worst provisions in the original ERA were removed as a
result of concerns expressed by business and other groups.
Some, like the protection afforded to workers involved in
the sale or transfer of a business, have now been revived in
the bill. Second, the impact of the ERA has been limited by
the narrower interpretation of ‘good faith’ by the courts.
This interpretation has been highlighted as the reason for
the greater emphasis on good faith in the bill. Third, the
focus of bargaining under the ERA remained the enterprise.
In contrast, the bill strongly promotes multi-employer
bargaining.
2.3 While there was much scare-mongering
among unions, academics and politicians at the time the
Employment Contracts Act (ECA) was passed, it proved to be
groundless. High levels of satisfaction with its operation
were reported in surveys. The ECA was a major factor in the
growth in employment and the decline in unemployment that
characterised the 1990s. It was also a significant
contributor to post-1993 productivity growth.
2.4 A
recent Treasury report argued that the negative impact of
the proposed changes to the ERA would include an increase in
uncertainty around statutory obligations and an increase in
compliance and employment costs. According to the Treasury,
the cumulative impact of the changes to the ERA would be
modest. This comment is beside the point.
2.5 While the
full extent of any impact cannot be known, given the scale
of the changes and the scope for interpretation, the key
question relating to the bill is whether it moves New
Zealand’s labour market framework in the right direction or
the wrong one. The same question applied to the original
ERA and neither the Treasury nor the NZBR saw it as a
positive move. No single policy move, by itself, is likely
to have a large impact, either positively or negatively, on
economic performance. Cumulatively, however, sound or
unsound moves make a large difference – it is now well
established that the relative quality of policies and
institutions is the main determinant of differences in
countries’ economic performance. Continuous improvement in
policy settings, as in business, is essential to maintaining
international competitiveness. In our view the bill is a
backward move in terms of improving the environment for
growth, and the Treasury report is not in disagreement with
this assessment.
2.6 There is no evidence that the ERA
has made any contribution toward lifting economic growth,
which the government says is its top priority goal.
Indeed, the most recent Treasury forecasts suggest a
declining trend path for growth in GDP per capita, relative
to both current levels and those experienced over the past
10 years. The ERA has also had some adverse labour market
impacts, including generating an increase in the number of
person-days lost to work stoppages (see Figure 1).
Source: Statistics New Zealand
3. Key elements of the
Employment Relations Law Reform Bill
3.1 The bill amends
a number of provisions of the ERA, including the definition
of good faith, provisions relating to collective bargaining,
the resolution of employment relationship problems, and
protection of employees when businesses are sold.
3.2 Although the minister of labour has dubbed the bill
a ‘fine-tuning’ of the ERA, the proposed changes are
comprehensive and would constitute a significant alteration
of the labour relations landscape in New Zealand. That it
is more than fine-tuning is evident from the fact that the
bill proposes more than 40 changes to the ERA, while the
bill and its accompanying explanatory note total more than
100 pages.
3.3 A number of the key elements in the bill
are summarised below.
Good faith
3.4 The bill extends
the meaning of good faith in employment relationships beyond
the common law obligation of ‘mutual trust and confidence’.
Parties to the employment relationship are required to be
active and constructive in establishing and maintaining a
productive employment relationship by being responsive,
communicative and supportive. The bill specifies that the
duty of good faith may require a number of things,
including:
• the disclosure to employees of specific
information that may affect them; and
• the
requirement that the parties should bargain over all issues
between them rather than allowing specific matters to impede
further bargaining.
3.5 Breaches of good faith are
subject to fines. The bill also empowers the Employment
Relations Authority to fix the terms and conditions of a
collective agreement if there has been a breach of good
faith in relation to collective bargaining.
Promotion of
collective bargaining
3.6 One of the key aims of the bill
is to promote and encourage collective bargaining and
settlement. The bill provides strong incentives for parties
to enter into collective bargaining and to form collective
agreements. It also includes provisions to discourage and
penalise the “deliberate undermining and avoidance of
collective bargaining”. In particular, the bill:
• makes it clear that the process of collective
bargaining should result in a collective agreement unless
there is a genuine reason not to;
• requires that a
union and an employer "continue to bargain" about unresolved
matters even though they have come to a standstill or
reached a deadlock about a particular matter;
• enables
the Employment Relations Authority to provide assistance to
the parties in certain circumstances and make non-binding
recommendations for the settlement of matters in dispute
between
them;
• introduces several measures to
prevent the undermining of collective bargaining, including
classifying several types of behaviour in respect of
collective bargaining as being breaches of good faith;
• determines that it is a breach of good faith if
employers intentionally seek to undermine a collective
agreement by passing on the terms and conditions of a
collective agreement to employees on individual agreements;
• extends the definition of the coverage clause to cover
the work or type of work done by named employees;
• allows subsequent union and employer parties to join
existing collective agreements where the parties to the
original agreement have negotiated an enabling provision to
allow for this;
• amends the prohibition on preference
to allow collective agreements to contain more favourable
terms and conditions than individual agreements, thus
legitimising special one-off payments to public sector union
members;
• requires a first meeting if a multi-employer
collective agreement (MECA) is initiated or if bargaining
for one continues after a ballot. It is a breach of good
faith to fail, without reasonable excuse, to comply with
this requirement; and
• strengthens the effect of the ’30
day rule’ in the ERA, which provides new, non-union
employees with the terms and conditions of any collective
agreement that covers their work.
Employment
relationship problem resolution
3.7 In the area of
unjustified dismissals, the bill makes a number of changes,
including:
• a change in the test of whether or not a
dismissal is justifiable to one “determined on an objective
basis” that takes into account whether a dismissal was fair
and reasonable;
• introduction of a new remedy of
recommendations, which allows the Employment Relations
Authority/Court to recommend that an employer take actions
to prevent a similar employment relationship problem from
occurring where it has found that workplace factors were a
significant factor in the grievance; and
• measures aimed
at promoting the use of mediation and non-judicial problem
resolution services.
Continuity of employment
3.8 The
bill provides a two-tiered framework of employment
protection in restructuring situations:
• default
protective provisions will apply to most employees and
employers in the event of a sale, transfer of business or
initial contracting out of a business; and
• groups of
“vulnerable” employees (ie those in the cleaning, food
services and laundry sectors) will be given a higher level
of statutory protection. These "vulnerable" employees will
be given the right to transfer to their new employer on the
same terms and conditions that they enjoy with their current
employer.
4. The Employment Relations Law Reform Bill:
An assessment
4.1 In our view, the bill represents poor
public policy and should be withdrawn. We have several
concerns with the proposed changes:
(i) they lack a
sound policy basis;
(ii) they will worsen the business
environment in New Zealand and will have an adverse impact
on New Zealand’s growth prospects, thereby limiting its
ability to move into the top half of the OECD income
rankings; and
(iii) the process used to develop the bill
has been flawed and has been dominated by the Council of
Trade Unions (CTU), with little engagement being sought with
business.
(i) Lack of a sound policy basis
4.2 The
first broad concern with the proposed changes to the ERA is
that they lack a sound policy basis. In particular, the
changes do not appear to recognise the realities of the
current labour market.
4.3 The New Zealand labour
market has changed considerably in recent decades, with an
increasingly diverse workforce, a significant increase in
the labour force participation rate of women and an
increasing proportion of the workforce engaged in so-called
‘non-standard’ work such as part-time work and
self-employment.
4.4 The deregulation of the labour
market in 1991 through the ECA recognised the changing
realities of the labour market. It did so by putting in
place a regime under which employees and employers were free
to negotiate mutually beneficial employment arrangements,
including non-wage benefits such as parental leave, health
benefits and holiday entitlements.
4.5 The NZBR
strongly supports the continuation of such a system for
regulating employment relationships and the right of
employees and employers to freely negotiate terms and
conditions that suit them. In our view, a flexible and
voluntary system of negotiation over the terms and
conditions of employment contracts is the best way of
recognising the differing circumstances and preferences of
employees and firms and ensuring that the labour market is
able to evolve to meet the challenges of changing
circumstances.
4.6 The bill represents a further and
significant move away from the current, relatively
deregulated labour relations environment in New Zealand
toward a system of:
• compulsory unionism;
• compulsory arbitration; and
• national awards.
4.7 Each of these
is discussed briefly in turn.
Promotion of compulsory
unionism
4.8 The bill promotes compulsory unionism
through the union monopoly on collective agreements and the
statutory requirement for employers to bargain. This
promotion of compulsory unionism is occurring despite the
fact that unions are becoming less relevant in the modern
economy and rates of unionisation are dropping both in New
Zealand and worldwide. For example, union ‘density’ (the
proportion of potential union members who belong to a union)
in New Zealand dropped from 55.7 percent in September 1989
to 21.4 percent in December 1999 and has remained relatively
static since then. In 2002, only 21.7 percent of workers
belonged to a union. This number is even smaller in the
private sector, with only 12 percent of workers belonging to
unions.2
4.9 It is clear that one of the key motivations
of the ERA changes is to appease unions who are disgruntled
at this low ratio and the fact that it has not increased
despite the privileges granted to them under the ERA. The
law firm Simpson Grierson notes, “Unquestionably, the bill
provides a significant boost to the union movement”, and Ms
Wilson is on record as saying she envisages that union
density could rise to around 30 percent.
4.10 It is not
at all clear why increasing the number of unionised workers
would be a good thing. New Zealand workers – and
particularly those in the private sector – have moved on
from the 1970s/1980s mindset and have become sophisticated
participants in the modern labour market. Most now choose
individual contracts. Others judge that collective
representation can provide benefits, but that such
collectivisation need not be provided by a union. Indeed,
under the ECA, many workers used non-union bargaining
agents. Workers in the modern economy also recognise that
unions can hinder, rather than help the productivity growth
on which increases in wages depend and so may, in fact,
detract from their well-being.
Promotion of collective
bargaining
4.11 The bill aims to boost collective
bargaining through a statutory requirement to settle and
imposed settlements by the Employment Relations Authority.
As noted by law firm Simpson Grierson, “The right of
employers to say “no” to a collective agreement is also
significantly curtailed.” Employees’ freedom to choose
between individual and collective agreements is equally
affected. Individual contracts recognise the diverse needs,
interests and performance of firms and employees. There are
no sound public policy grounds for trying to tilt the
playing field towards collective bargaining.
Promotion
of national awards
4.12 The bill represents a move in the
direction of national awards. It does this through the
imposition of forced MECAs with subsequent party clauses.
Any employer who is asked must attend at least one meeting
and demonstrate good faith. If no agreement is reached, and
the Employment Relations Authority decides there is a breach
of good faith, such an agreement may be imposed.
4.13 This carries collectivism to new heights. There is
nothing wrong with firms in an industry coming together to
negotiate a broad agreement, but most don’t want to. Most
want to deal directly with their own employees, and vice
versa. The basis of this provision is transparent. The CTU
in its submission on the ERA review made it clear that its
ultimate agenda is “a return of the [national] award
system.”
Monopoly unionism
4.14 The bill’s explicit
agenda is to restore, through government fiat, privileges
that ordinary workers have refused to confer on unions, as
exemplified by the ongoing decline in union density since
the deregulation of the labour market in 1991.
4.15 One
of the benefits claimed by unionists is that they can lift
wages through the creation of monopolies, which give them
greater bargaining power vis-à-vis employers. Such monopoly
pressure can only be exercised by unions if they can
restrict the supply of labour. They can do this in one of
two ways:
• by making it harder for non-union labour to
get jobs at all. The proposed changes to the ERA attempt to
do this by making it more difficult for employees to work
under an individual contract (ie removal of prohibition on
preference, provisions surrounding undermining of collective
contracts, etc); and
• by stopping anyone from
undercutting the cost of union labour. The proposed changes
to the ERA attempt to do this in a number of ways including
through the provisions relating to employees involved in the
transfer or sale of a business.
4.16 The advent of market
reforms such as deregulation, globalisation and the removal
of trade restrictions worldwide has meant that the position
of unions is tenuous. They are finding it ever more
difficult to sustain a monopoly position in the labour
market. Efforts to buttress it by legislation will
ultimately prove fruitless, but will reduce the flexibility
and growth potential of the economy.
False underlying
assumptions
4.17 Not only is the bill out of step with
modern labour market realities, it is also based on the
false premise that labour markets are special; are
characterised by unequal bargaining power between employers
and employees; and require special regulation to promote
unionisation and collective bargaining to offset this
inequality.
4.18 The idea of unequal bargaining power is
explicitly incorporated in the ERA and proposed amendments.
It also underlies other labour market legislation such as
the Holidays Act. The notion of unequal bargaining power in
the labour market is something that is asserted by the
government, but has never been explained or defended. It is
refuted by a vast body of law and economics
scholarship.
4.19 The idea owes its origins to Marxist
economics. Marx saw the world in terms of a class struggle
between workers and owners of capital. Employers had the
upper hand and would ‘exploit’ workers. The wages of
workers would be driven down to subsistence levels, and they
would become “wage slaves”.
4.20 Facts soon demonstrated
that Marx was wrong. Wages rose strongly even in his
lifetime. In the modern era, Hong Kong is a country where
unions hardly exist but wage levels are among the highest in
the world. The fallacy in the notion of unequal bargaining
power is obvious. As University of Chicago legal scholar
Richard Epstein has stated:
If such an inequality did
govern the employment relationship, we should expect to see
conditions that exist in no labour market. Wages would be
driven to zero, for no matter what their previous level, the
employer could use his (inexhaustible) bargaining power to
reduce them further, until the zero level was reached.
Similarly, inequality of bargaining power implies that the
employee will be bound for a term while the employer …
retains the power to terminate at will. Yet in practice we
observe both positive wages and employees with the right to
quit at will.3
4.21 In competitive labour markets, the
reality is that employers compete with one another for
workers, and workers compete with one another for jobs.
Wages are driven up by productivity increases and
competition for scarce labour. At times there may be a
buyer’s market or a seller’s market for particular skills in
particular locations. But there is no systematic advantage
for one side over another, otherwise wages would never rise,
and there is nothing special
in any relevant
economic sense about employment contracts.
4.22 The
notion of unequal bargaining power is not supported by
theory and evidence. It is even less credible when examined
in the context of the current New Zealand labour market,
which is characterised by low unemployment, labour shortages
in many occupations and regions, as well as a large number
of small employers.
4.23 A second misconception that
flows from the unequal bargaining power fallacy is that
‘take-it-or-leave-it’ offers from employers are ‘bad’. This
belief does not recognise that, as consumers, we face
take-it-or-leave-it transactions every time we deal with
businesses such as banks or supermarkets. It is the most
common form of transaction in the marketplace. It respects
property rights and freedom to contract, and is in no way
coercive. Neither workers nor consumers are exploited in
competitive markets: an employee or consumer who can go
elsewhere is very hard to exploit.
(ii) Impact on
economic growth
4.24 The government has stated that
economic growth "remains a top policy priority".4 The Speech
from the Throne at the opening of the current parliament
stated that the government:
... sees its most important
task as building the conditions for increasing New Zealand's
long term sustainable rate of economic growth.
The
government has amplified this statement by saying its goal
is to see New Zealand attain a level of income per capita in
the top half of the member countries of the Organisation for
Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD).
4.25 The
test of any policy should therefore be whether or not it
assists in moving the country toward this laudable and
ambitious goal.
4.26 The proposed changes to the ERA
fail this test. Indeed, the changes are far more likely to
reduce the growth rate of the economy and frustrate the
attainment of this goal. As a result, wages will be lower
than otherwise and, as a country, we will be less able to
afford services such as better schools and better health
care.
4.27 Collectively, the proposed changes to the
ERA will mean a less flexible workforce, through their
promotion of collective bargaining, unionisation and
multi-employer collective agreements. The narrower
definition of ‘justifiability’ in the area of personal
grievances will mean it is harder to dismiss workers. The
changes will lead to greater uncertainty for employers as
new legal interpretations are developed in areas such as
personal grievances, ‘good faith’ and bargaining (eg what
constitutes ‘undermining’ of a collective agreement).
4.28 The new protections afforded to workers in the
event of contracting out or the sale or transfer of a
business will have a significant impact on the ability of
firms, and the economy more generally, to adapt and
restructure. They will also reduce the economic value of
firms in the sectors covered by the new provisions and the
incentive to invest in them.
4.29 The disincentive to
invest will apply to a wider set of industries than those
identified in the bill. This is because the minister of
labour can add to the categories of employees listed in
Schedule 1 of the bill. Firms will have far less of an
incentive to invest in firms in sectors that could be
‘threatened’ by such regulation.
4.30 The bill’s
expansion of the role of ‘third parties’ such as the
Employment Relations Authority and the courts is a move back
toward compulsory arbitration. This is detrimental to the
effective operation of business given that third parties:
• do not possess either the information or business
expertise required to make informed decisions;
• are not
well placed to judge what the ‘right’ outcome should be in
particular cases; and
• do not face the consequences of
their decisions.
4.31 The increased involvement of third
parties could have adverse effects on the behaviour of
employers and unions during bargaining or disputes and lead
to unproductive strategic behaviour.
4.32 The ERA bill’s
proposed changes will lead to higher administration and
compliance costs for employers. For example:
• the
provisions relating to ‘undermining’ of collective contracts
will require employers to negotiate (or at least be seen to
be negotiating) separately with each employee working on an
individual contract – a time-consuming and potentially
wasteful exercise;
• the requirement that employment
agreements must contain employment protection provisions
will take time and cost to implement. It will also lock
firms into a process that may not be appropriate given that
employers cannot foresee the circumstances surrounding sales
and transfers that will occur in the future.
4.33 Additional compliance and direct costs would come on
top of cost increases associated with a series of labour
market and other changes that the government has introduced
in recent years, including:
• the re-nationalisation of
ACC;
• successive large increases in minimum wages,
especially for people under 21 years of age;
• the
increase in the top income tax rate to 39 percent;
• the
introduction of an extra week of holidays and changes to the
Holidays Act;
• the introduction of parental benefits;
and
• changes to the Health and Safety in Employment Act.
The government has also signalled the possible
introduction of a pay equity policy. While the current
proposal is that pay equity, if introduced, would apply only
to the state sector, it would still have a significant
impact on private sector firms which will need to compete
for staff with public sector organisations in a distorted
labour market.
4.34 Collectively, these changes, along
with other anti-growth policies, have adversely affected the
operating environment for business in New Zealand.
According to Business New Zealand, an average New Zealand
company faced additional costs of over $26,000 over the
three calendar years 2000-2002.5 In addition, the Business
New Zealand - KPMG Compliance Cost Survey of August 2003
found that:
• the average enterprise spent over 1,300
hours on compliance requirements; and
• respondents’
annual compliance burden came to $52,724 per annum ($812 per
employee).
4.35 On a per-employee basis, compliance
costs were higher for small firms. Nearly 30 percent of
compliance costs were employment-related. Nearly all
respondents considered that there had been an increase or no
change in compliance costs in the last year.6 The proposed
changes to the ERA would exacerbate this trend.
4.36 The proposed changes to the ERA and the wider
labour market reforms represent a move toward a ‘European’
model of labour market regulation. This is occurring at the
very time that the weaknesses in that model are becoming
more obvious in countries such as France, Italy and Germany
and commentators are recommending wholesale changes to the
system.7 Indeed, the German government recently introduced
some changes aimed at reducing the unemployment benefit and
giving added flexibility for employers to hire and fire
workers.8
4.37 According to a 2001 study, New Zealand
is already at a competitive disadvantage when it comes to
labour market institutions such as social welfare and
industrial relations arrangements. The study showed that
New Zealand was poorly placed in international comparisons
of strictness of eligibility criteria for unemployment
insurance and suspension of unemployment insurance payments,
and only moderately well placed in the late 1990s in terms
of strictness of employment protection for regular
employment.9
4.38 In the Fraser Institute’s Economic
Freedom of the World 2003 Annual Report, New Zealand was
placed only 21st in the category of labour market
regulations, which measures economic freedom in the areas of
minimum wages, hiring and firing practices, the share of the
labour force whose wages are set by centralised collective
bargaining and the extent to which the unemployment benefit
preserves the incentive to work. New Zealand’s ranking
compares with that of Hong Kong (2nd), the United States
(3rd) and the United Kingdom (5th).10 Recent and proposed
labour market reforms will make the overall ranking of
labour market institutions in New Zealand even less
favourable.
4.39 An increase in the degree of labour
market regulation is likely to have an adverse impact on the
rate of economic growth in New Zealand. A recent OECD
report examined the impact of policy and institutional
settings in both the product and labour markets on
productivity and firm dynamics. This work was part of a
broader project which aimed to identify the sources of
economic growth in OECD countries. The objective of the
exercise was to explain the reasons for different growth
experiences across the OECD and to identify policies,
institutions and other factors that could contribute to
enhancing long-term growth prospects.
4.40 Key findings
from that work are that:
• strict employment protection
legislation, by reducing employment turnover, may in a
number of circumstances lead to a lower productivity
performance and discourage the entry of firms;
• there is
evidence that high hiring and firing costs weaken
productivity performance, especially when wages and/or
internal training do not offset these higher costs, thereby
inducing sub-optimal adjustments of the workforce to
technology changes and less incentive to innovate;
• the
negative impact of strict employment protection laws on
productivity is stronger in countries with an intermediate
degree of centralisation/coordination; and
• employment
protection regulations mainly affect market access of small
and medium-sized firms. 11
4.41 Recent empirical work in
10 OECD countries shows that countries with low
administrative barriers, pro-competition sector-specific
regulations and flexible hiring and firing rules typically
experienced higher entry rates of small sized firms.12
4.42 This evidence is consistent with a World Bank study
from the 1980s that found that countries with inflexible
labour markets suffered a penalty of 1.4 percentage points
in their annual growth rates.
4.43 Overly strict
employment protection policies can also have adverse effects
on an economy’s ability to innovate. This is of concern
given that innovation is recognised as one of the most
important sources of economic growth. As noted in a recent
OECD report:
… policies that make hiring and firing
difficult can increase the cost of implementing innovations,
when these require labour downsizing or reorganisation; and
policies that favour the bargaining power of insiders can
reduce the ability of firms to appropriate innovation rents,
especially when post-innovation wage re-negotiation is
possible …13
4.44 The OECD notes that the effect of
entry regulations is particularly important for productivity
performance in industries in which technology is evolving
rapidly, such as information and communication technology
(ICT) industries. Furthermore, the OECD notes that product
and labour market policies can also affect the propensity of
a country to concentrate production in innovative
industries, by, for instance, affecting the pace of resource
allocation in the economy.14
4.45 The introduction of
stricter employment protection policies is therefore working
at cross purposes with at least two of the areas that are
seen as critical to the government’s growth and innovation
framework, namely:
• enhancing the innovation system in
all areas of the economy; and
• strengthening
foundational areas, with priority given to policy
initiatives that will promote further increases in
sustainable economic growth.15
(iii) Flawed policy
development process
4.46 A flawed process was followed
in the development of the bill. In particular, we are
concerned about the short timeline to make submissions on
the bill, the extent to which the policy development process
has been dominated by discussions with the Council of Trade
Unions, and the fact that there has been little or no
engagement with business over what would amount to
significant changes to the industrial relations environment
in New Zealand.
Short deadline for submissions
4.47 The timeline provided for business organisations to
develop a response to the bill has been inadequate. The
bill was presented to parliament last December and
organisations were given less than three months to respond
to the changes – a period that included the run-up to
Christmas and the holiday period.
4.48 This is of
concern given both the extent and complex nature of the
changes to the ERA. The experience with the changes to the
Holidays Act suggests that many employers are only now –
some months after the passage of the Holidays Bill – coming
to grips with their full implications.
4.49 Although
employer organisations, including the NZBR, asked for an
extension of the deadline for submissions beyond 27
February, none has been granted.
Union domination of the
policy development process
4.50 A key concern with the
bill is the fact that the policy development process has
been dominated by the Council of Trade Unions (CTU), as
exemplified by the bill’s content.
4.51 As revealed by
NZBR research in late January, the CTU presented a shopping
list of labour law demands in a December 2002 submission and
its views have clearly dominated the development of the
bill. There are startling similarities between the CTU
submission and the bill. The broad objectives and policy
directions of each document are largely consistent, and in
key instances the drafting is identical.
4.52 All of
the areas of concern outlined in the December 2002 CTU
submission are addressed in the bill:
• an expansion of
the interpretation of good faith;
• provisions to favour
collective bargaining over individual agreements and to
encourage multi-employer collective agreements;
• more
onerous unjustifiable dismissal provisions;
• moves to
eliminate so-called ‘free riding’ by non-union employees;
and
• restrictions on contracting out and the sale of a
business.
4.53 Several examples show the degree to
which unions’ views have been incorporated in the bill.
4.54 The ERA introduced the concept of ‘good faith’ into
employment law. Courts were forced to define that term, and
mostly based their judgments on the common law test of
mutual trust and confidence. In response to parliamentary
question 2132 on 16 February 2000, minister of labour
Margaret Wilson said that employment relationships should be
based on principles of “mutual trust and confidence”. The
courts were therefore presumably acting in a way that was
consistent with the minister’s views at the time. However,
this was not strong enough for the CTU and their wish to
introduce a higher standard was carried out to the letter.
Courts would have an even greater role in determining
whether the duty of ‘good faith’ has been met.
4.55 As
noted above, union representation has fallen considerably
since the 1980s and has barely recovered under the ERA, with
only one worker in five now belonging to a union. The CTU,
in its December 2002 submission, sought two changes to
further shift the balance away from individual contracts and
toward union-negotiated collective contracts:
• it
asked for the legislation to clearly state that employers
had no need to pass on superior terms and conditions from
collective contracts to employees on individual contracts.
This exact change was made in the bill; and
• it
requested that the legislation state: “an employer cannot
pass on the same terms and conditions, or substantially
similar terms and conditions agreed as a settlement for a
collective agreement … to employees not covered by the
collective agreement, without the written agreement of the
union or union parties to the collective agreement”. In
other words, unions should have the power to approve
individual contracts.
4.56 In this case, the CTU was
given what it asked for, though through a less direct route
than the explicit requirement of union ‘sign-off’. Instead,
an employer breaches the duty of ‘good faith’ if he or she
extends the provisions of a collective agreement to other
employees in order to “undermine the collective agreement”.
Such slippery wording means huge scope for interpretation in
individual cases and great uncertainty for employers. It
also means that the only insurance for employers against
getting bogged down in legal hassles is getting union
sign-off of individual contracts. This would lead to an
absurd, almost Orwellian situation where unions hold sway
over non-members’ contracts.
4.57 Finally, the CTU wanted
more ‘face-time’ with union members, at company expense. It
asked that employers be instructed that they could not dock
wages of union members who held meetings during work time,
and that the legislation state that an employee eligible for
education leave would be “an employee who is a member of a
union.” Policymakers rubber-stamped these two
changes.
4.58 Further examples of the considerable
overlap between CTU demands and the bill’s content are
available on the New Zealand Business Roundtable website
(http://www.nzbr.org.nz/documents/features/ctu_submission.asp).
4.59 In contrast, the views of business have not been
incorporated at all in the bill. Even the modest reform
suggestions that were put forward by Business New Zealand at
the time of the ERA Review were rejected. These
recommendations included:
• that any group of
employees, whether or not members of a registered union,
should be able to bargain collectively with their
employer;
• that the concept of ‘good faith’ require an
employer who does not wish to negotiate a collective
agreement to meet with the union to discuss the matter but
not to go through the exercise of considering the detail of
individual clauses;
• that the formulation of bargaining
claims and reporting back on negotiations be done either
during one or both of the legislatively provided union
meetings (section 26 of the Act) or outside work time to
avoid adverse effects on productivity;
• that recognition
be given to the fact that the so-called ‘balance of power’
now frequently lies with employees and that, at the least, a
salary bar above which personal grievance and employment
agreement provisions do not apply should be reintroduced;
and
• that the legislation provide for an effective
probationary period when the Act’s personal grievance
provisions do not apply.
5. Conclusions and
recommendations
5.1 In 1999, the OECD argued that the
employment relations framework that existed under the ECA
was “sound”. The ERA, introduced in October 2000,
represented a step in the wrong direction for labour
relations law in New Zealand. The changes proposed in the
bill represent a further move away from the decentralised
and flexible labour relations system that existed under the
ECA.
5.2 In its most recent report on New Zealand, the
OECD expressed a similar view, noting that:
Although the
labour market remains one of the most flexible in the OECD,
recent years have seen a clear trend towards greater
rigidities and higher labour costs. Further such changes
are in the pipeline. Individually the measures have been
fairly benign, but cumulatively their impact may be
important … social objectives need to be balanced against
the benefits of labour market flexibility – namely faster
productivity growth and a more stable and resilient
economy.16
5.3 We agree with the OECD’s assessment. The
changes proposed in the bill will harm employers, employees
and the national interest. They will do nothing to assist
the government in meeting its ambitious target of restoring
New Zealand to the top half of the OECD in terms of GDP per
capita. Indeed, they will have the opposite effect by
reducing the economy’s ability to adapt to frequently
changing market conditions in the world economy.
5.4 This is not to say that the sky will fall if the
bill is passed into law. The NZBR did not predict that in
its comments on the ERA in 2000 and we are not saying that
now. We did not and do not intend to make the kind of
exaggerated and nonsensical claims that were made by those
who opposed the ECA when it was introduced. However, the
evidence suggests that the changes will have an adverse
impact on New Zealand’s ability to innovate and grow.
5.5 The proposed changes seem unlikely to represent an
end point for policy. The December 2002 CTU submission
makes it clear that in the CTU’s agenda they are but a
stepping stone on a path back to the world of national
awards, compulsory unionism and compulsory arbitration that
existed in the 1970s and 1980s. At the behest of the CTU,
the provisions relating to the sale or transfer of a
business, which were removed from the Employment Relations
Bill in 2000, have returned in modified form in this bill.
The introduction of paid parental leave in 2002 provides
further evidence of CTU influence, with the prime minister
recently indicating that the government is looking at
expanding the scheme.17 The government has consistently
followed the CTU’s bidding.
5.6 For the reasons outlined
in this submission, we consider that the Employment
Relations Law Reform Bill is not in the national interest
(as opposed to the interests of the CTU). It does not meet
standard public policy criteria of efficiency, equity and
individual freedom. We consider that the committee should
not get lost in the detail of this complex bill. It should
instead focus on the ‘big picture’. The fundamental
question to be asked of the proposed changes to the ERA is
whether they will promote a more prosperous New Zealand. We
submit that they do not and that the bill should not
proceed. Instead, we submit that a fundamental review of
the ERA and its underlying principles should be undertaken.
The review should address weaknesses in the current labour
relations legal framework and should involve input from all
interested parties.