2025 Taskforce Report: Questions and Answers
2025 Taskforce Report: Focusing on Growth Questions and
Answers
General policy
questions
Q: What’s new in this report? How has
your thinking evolved?
This second report more fully
articulates the context for the recommendations in last
year’s report and outlines the case for reform in more
detail. It looks more deeply into what a “focus on
growth” means, and identifies seven key areas where
serious progress is needed if we are serious about closing
the gap.
The report also:
• updates New Zealand’s
productivity statistics and growth projections using the
latest data;
• outlines lessons from the latest
literature on economic growth and
innovation;
• assesses the impact of economic geography
on New Zealand’s growth;
• examines the case for
‘smart active government’; and
• highlights the
importance of reducing the large structural fiscal
deficits.
Q: Has the income gap with Australia widened
or closed? What explains the change over the last year? How
should this be interpreted?
In our first report, we
noted that real GDP per capita in 2008 was 35 percent higher
in Australia than in New Zealand based on OECD data. Over
recent years, the New Zealand economy has experienced a
recession, and grown only slowly coming out of it, whereas
the Australian economy has continued to grow. The OECD is
projecting the gap to widen to 42 percent by 2025 – this
is in line with other forecasters. As a result, we do not
see any realistic possibility that the gap in real per
capita income has narrowed in the past year.
Year to
year fluctuations in the income gap have occurred and will
continue to occur. All sorts of factors affect these annual
fluctuations, and only some will reflect anything about the
relative strengths of the policy frameworks in the two
countries. For this reason, in terms of things like the
2025 goal changes in the income gap are most meaningfully
interpreted over the medium term.
Q: Is New Zealand on
track to close the per capita GDP gap with Australia by
2025? If we do nothing significantly different, are we on
track to maintain our relative income position versus
Australia?
We do not think the gap will narrow based
on current policy settings. In fact, there is a significant
risk that it may widen over the years ahead. Based on OECD
projections, on current policy settings, the gap in terms of
GDP per capita is projected to increase to 42 percent by
2025 (from 35 percent in 2008).
Q: What does the
current income gap, and the projected increase in the gap,
mean for New Zealanders?
It means that those living
in New Zealand cannot afford the same standard of living –
quality housing, education, medical care, infrastructure,
etc. – as in Australia. It means that to earn the same,
New Zealanders would have to work many more hours. It
therefore affects the incentives for New Zealanders to
either stay in New Zealand or move to Australia. If the gap
continues to widen, we estimate that a net 412,000 New
Zealanders could leave New Zealand for Australia over the
next 15 years.
Q: Is it realistic that New Zealand
could catch up with Australia by 2025 in terms of GDP per
capita?
There is no reason why we cannot catch up.
New Zealand has most of the advantages and disadvantages
that Australia has – both have basically sound economic
and social institutions, abundant natural resources, hard
working, creative and increasingly well-educated people, and
both countries are small by global standards and similarly
distant from their major markets.
Many of the policies
we need to adopt are already in place in Australia and other
developed economies. To grow much faster than Australia,
which is forecast to achieve relatively strong growth to
2025, our policies will need to be among the best in the
world. We can choose to adopt such policies – the choice
is ours.
Q: What would be required for New Zealand to
catch Australia in terms of GDP per capita?
New
Zealand needs to grow slightly more than two percent per
capita per annum faster than Australia. Achieving this
requires:
• Unwavering focus on pro-growth policies.
Strong political leadership is needed to ensure a consistent
policy focus on creating the environment in which the
private sector can thrive, driving productivity, sustainable
employment creation and growth.
• A major lift in
labour productivity (output per worker). Increases in labour
productivity, and the private capital investment associated
with it, are strongly influenced by policy choices. All
policy decisions should be made with this focus on
productivity in mind.
To catch Australia, the Taskforce
considers that the seven key areas to focus on are:
• reducing government spending and
tax;
• reviewing the boundary between the private and
public sectors;
• more robust and transparent analysis
of infrastructure proposals;
• creating an environment
where firms want to invest more in R & D
• remove
unnecessary regulatory barriers to private sector
investment;
• welcoming foreign investors on the same
terms as domestic investors;
• creating world-leading
institutions to strengthen the durability of good
policy.
Q: What explains New Zealand’s income gap
with Australia? What about those reasons posed by others to
explain the gap such as New Zealand’s size and distance
from other markets and Australia’s mineral resources –
why does the Taskforce reject these?
There is no
definitive evidence that explains the evolution of the gap
fully satisfactorily. The Taskforce has looked carefully at
all the plausible explanations and concluded that poor
policy choices by successive governments are the primary
cause.
European Union: In the 1960s and early
1970s, Australia had its first mineral boom, sparked
initially by the Australian Government’s decision to
remove export controls on coal. At the same time, New
Zealand’s terms of trade fell sharply in the late 1960s
and again in the mid 1970s, coupled with the reduction of
our biggest export market when the United Kingdom entered
the EEC, hit New Zealand hard. These two events occurred
within a few years of each other , and contributed
substantially to the gap opening up.
Reforms: The
policy reforms in the 1980s and early 1990s helped New
Zealand gain back some ground, slowing the overall rate of
decline relative to other countries. New Zealand achieved
strong productivity gains relative to Australia following
the economic reforms of the 1980s, especially in those
sectors most open to competition. But since 1995 New
Zealand has fallen behind as Australia has continued to
reform its economic policies and institutions while New
Zealand has taken a breather. Since around 1990, New
Zealand’s per capita growth rates have matched those of
the average OECD country, but have still lagged a little
behind those of Australia.
Size and distance: In a
global context, Australia is similarly disadvantaged by its
small size and distance from major markets like New Zealand,
so size and distance from markets cannot explain
Australia’s superior performance. By the same token, size
and distance also need not be obstacles to closing the gap
– if Australia can do it, so can
we.
Commodities: Some people claim that our
commodity-centred economy is to blame. The evidence does not
support this: commodity products are an unusually high
proportion of exports in both New Zealand and Australia.
New Zealand’s terms of trade have improved quite steadily
since the mid 1980s, following a very similar pattern to
those in Australia until the last 5 years or so, so
differences in the terms of trade cannot explain the gap.
Minerals: In contrast to many popular views about
Australia’s advantages, New Zealand is relatively well
endowed with natural resources – on a per-capita basis
perhaps better endowed than Australia. Many high-income
countries have much smaller mineral resources than New
Zealand, e.g. Singapore, Taiwan, Japan, Denmark, Ireland,
and Austria. The Taskforce’s view, having looked into
this, is that the claims that minerals have made the
difference are exaggerated.
Chapter 4 of this year’s
report discusses this in more detail.
Q: How much of
the relative economic performance of the two nations has
been driven by changes in relative terms of trade and net
migration patterns, rather than by government policies on
both sides of the Tasman?
Australia’s and New
Zealand’s terms of trade tracked together until 2003 (see
chart below) – so terms of trade wouldn’t appear to
explain the gap, which opened up largely prior to 2003. Net
migration is more a reflection of economic performance
rather than a driver – if our economic performance
improves relative to Australia, we would expect the net
outward migration flow of New Zealanders to reduce.
Q:
Is action required across all the policy fronts identified
in the Taskforce’s report in order to narrow the income
gap? Are some recommendations more critical than others –
and if so, which ones?
The Taskforce believes that to
catch Australia, New Zealand will need to have a
growth-friendly policy environment that is second to none
– and that this is perfectly realistic. We don’t say
that progress is needed instantly in all seven of the key
areas that we have identified – that is not realistic. But
we do consider that significant progress in all these areas
will be needed if we are to catch up, and that we need to
start now.
Q: What role does the exchange rate play in
the story?
A high real exchange rate is often a
feature of a successful and high-performing economy. In an
economy experiencing consistently rapid productivity growth,
a rising real exchange rate is how the fruits of economic
success are distributed round the economy. Over recent
decades, New Zealand’s productivity performance has been
quite poor, reflected in the wide gap that has opened up
between our incomes and those of other advanced countries
since the 1970s. Economic literature and international
experience suggest that we should have expected to see a
falling real exchange rate, as part of the mechanism by
which New Zealand adjusted to that decline, and rebalanced
(making consumption relatively less attractive and
production relatively more attractive) to help reverse the
decline. That has not happened (see chart below). In the
last few years, the shift back to large fiscal deficits has
exacerbated this imbalance.
The sorts of reforms proposed
by the Taskforce are designed to improve the overall
competitiveness of doing business in New Zealand. If
successfully implemented, they could be expect to close the
gap between the real exchange rate and our relative economic
performance.
Real exchange rate behaviour over periods of
decades has nothing to do with how, say, monetary policy is
conducted. Monetary policy has a decisive effect on the
nominal exchange rate, and can affect the real exchange rate
for periods of up to a few years, but longer-term trends in
the real exchange rate reflects real economic factors
only.
Q: Did the Taskforce consider options for
better managing New Zealand’s exchange rate?
Yes.
In our first report, we looked at a variety of options that
submitters and others think could achieve a less variable
exchange rate. Some – notably a Singapore-style managed
rate – would simply not work in New Zealand. Others –
notably currency union with Australia or the United States
– could generate some gains but would also come with very
substantial risks of the sort apparent in Europe. On balance
the Taskforce thinks that at this stage they are not worth
the cost. Data suggest that the exchange rate is probably
not materially more variable than the exchange rates of many
other advanced economies.
Administrative
questions
Q: What is the total budget of the 2025
Taskforce?
$477,000 from establishment in 2009 to
June 2012 (excluding GST).
Q: How much has been spent
on this year’s report?
The budget for this year’s
report is $164,000 (excluding GST). We are on track to spend
around that amount on this year’s report.
Q: When
was the Taskforce established and how often has it
met?
The Taskforce was announced on 21 July 2009. For
last year’s report, the Taskforce met 11 times (between 7
September and 23 November 2009). For this year’s report,
the Taskforce has met a further 10 times.
Process
questions
Q: How were decisions made by the
Taskforce regarding policy recommendations? Was it all by
consensus after discussion, or were there occasions when a
vote had to be taken?
The report represents the
collective view of the Taskforce – no votes were
taken.
Q: Will the Taskforce issue further
reports?
The Taskforce was established in 2009 for a
period of three years. This is the Taskforce’s second
report (in its second year). The Taskforce is required by
its Terms of Reference to report again next year (by the end
of October
2011).
ends